E-books and e-publishing by Samuel Vaknin (summer reading list txt) đ
- Author: Samuel Vaknin
- Performer: -
Book online «E-books and e-publishing by Samuel Vaknin (summer reading list txt) đ». Author Samuel Vaknin
intelligence) - preferably including itself, the user, and
their cumulative interactions.
It must regard all other âintelligentâ machines in its
âworldâ (the user being only one of them) as its âclientsâ.
It must, therefore, be able to communicate with them in a
natural language.
Its universe must be seamless (e.g., the physical or even
system location of files or hardware or software or applets or
servers or communication lines or information and so on - will
be irrelevant).
It will probably be peer-orientated (no hierarchy).
I call it âthe intuitive universal interfaceâ.
The new media technologies were designed by engineers and
programmers - not by marketing people and users. The interface
of the future will reflect the needs, wishes, limitations, and
skills of users. This is a revolutionary shift and a natural
outcome of the takeover of the Internet by governments and
bottom line orientated corporations. The interface of the
future will seek to enhance usage and enrich the userâs
experience - not to win technological beauty contest. It is a
welcome transition - and long overdue.
Internet Advertising - What Went Wrong?
By: Sam Vaknin
The decline in Internet advertising - though paralleled by a
similar trend in print advertising - had more serious and
irreversible implications. Most content dot.coms were based on
ad-driven revenue models. Online advertising was supposed to
amortize startup and operational costs and lead to
profitability even as it subsidized free access to costly
content.
A similar revenue model has been successfully propping up
print periodicals for at least two centuries. But, as opposed
to their online counterparts, print products have a few
streams of income, not least among them paid subscriptions.
Moreover, print media kept their costs down in good times and
bad. Dot.coms devoured their investorsâ money in a self-destructive and avaricious bacchanalia.
But why did online advertising collapse in the first place?
Was it ineffective?
Advertising is a multi-faceted and psychologically complex
phenomenon. It imparts information to potential consumers,
users, suppliers, investors, the community, or other
stakeholders in the firm. It motivates each of these to do his
bit: consumers to consume, investors to invest and so on.
But this is not the main function of the advertising dollar.
Modern economic signal theory has cast advertising in a new
and surprising - though by no means counterintuitive - light.
According to this theory, the role of advertising is to signal
to the marketplace the advertiserâs resilience, longevity,
wealth, clout, and dominance. By splurging money of
advertising, the advertiser actually informs us - the
âeyeballsâ - that it is here to stay, sufficiently affluent to
finance its ads, stable, reliable, and dominant.
âIf firm X invested a million bucks in advertising - it must
be worth more than a million bucksâ - goes the signal. âIf it
invested so much money in promoting its products, it is not a
fly-by-nightâ. âIf it can throw money at an ad campaign, it is
stable and resilientâ.
This signal is missing in online advertising. It drowns in
noise. The online noise to signal ratio was unacceptable to
advertisers - so they stopped advertising. When the noise to
signal ratio tops a certain level - ads cease to be effective.
The readers or spectators become inured to the messages - both
explicit and implicit. They tune off.
The noise in online advertising stems from two sources.
A critical element in the signal is lost if the ad is not paid
for. Only paid advertising conveys information about the
purported health and prospects of the advertiser. Yet, the
Internet is flooded with free advertising: free classifieds,
free banner ads, ad exchanges. The paid ads drown in this
ocean of free ads. There is often no way of telling a paid ad
from a free one - without reading the fine print.
Moreover, Internet users are a âcaptive audienceâ. It is easy
to flip ad-besieged channels on TV, or turn the ad-laden leaf
of a newspaper. It is close to impossible to avoid an ad on
the Net. Banner ads are an integral part of the page. Pop-up
ads pop up. Embedded ads are embedded. One needs to install
special applications to avoid the harassment.
This leads to desensitization and a revolt of the user. Users
resent the intrusion, are incensed by the coercive tactics of
advertisers, nerve wrecked by protracted download times, and
unnerved by the content of many of the ads. This is not an
environment conducive to clinching deals or converting to
sales.
There is also the issue of credibility. The bulk of online
advertising emanates from dot.coms. Even prior to the recent
stock exchange meltdown, these were not considered paragons of
rectitude and truth in advertising. People learned to distrust
most of what they read in Internet ads. Scorched by scams,
false promises, faulty products, shoddy or non-existent
customer care, broken links, or all of the above - users
learned to ignore Web advertising and relegate it to their
mental dust bins.
More about credibility on the Web here:
The InCredible Web
Will the medium ever recover? Probably not. As the Internet is
taken over by brick-and-mortar corporations and governments,
online fare will come to resemble the offline sort. Online ads
will be no more than interactive renditions of their offline
facsimiles. The revenue model will switch from advertising to
subscriptions and âauthor-paysâ. The days of free content
financed by advertising are over.
This does not mean that the days of free content are over as
well. It only means that new, improved, realistic, and
clutter-free revenue models will have to be found. There are
some interesting developments in scholarly online publishing
as well as in the fields of online reference and self-publishing. But these are early days and the medium is
dynamic. Ad-driven content was a failure. The next model may
be a roaring success - or yet another dismal defeat.
The Economics of Spam
By: Sam Vaknin
Also published by United Press International (UPI)
Tennessee resident K. C. âKhanâ Smith owes the internet
service provider EarthLink $24 million. According to the CNN,
last August he was slapped with a lawsuit accusing him of
violating federal and state Racketeering Influenced and
Corrupt Organizations (RICO) statutes, the federal Computer
Fraud and Abuse Act of 1984, the federal Electronic
Communications Privacy Act of 1986 and numerous other state
laws. On July 19 - having failed to appear in court - the
judge ruled against him. Mr. Smith is a spammer.
Brightmail, a vendor of e-mail filters and anti-spam
applications warned that close to 5 million spam âattacksâ or
âburstsâ occurred last month and that spam has mushroomed 450
percent since June last year. PC World concurs. Between one
seventh and one half of all e-mail messages are spam -
unsolicited and intrusive commercial ads, mostly concerned
with sex, scams, get rich quick schemes, financial services
and products, and health articles of dubious provenance. The
messages are sent from spoofed or fake e-mail addresses. Some
spammers hack into unsecured servers - mainly in China and
Korea - to relay their missives anonymously.
Spam is an industry. Mass e-mailers maintain lists of e-mail
addresses, often âharvestedâ by spamware bots - specialized
computer applications - from Web sites. These lists are rented
out or sold to marketers who use bulk mail services. They come
cheap - c. $100 for 10 million addresses. Bulk mailers provide
servers and bandwidth, charging c. $300 per million messages
sent.
As spam recipients become more inured, ISPâs less tolerant,
and both more litigious - spammers multiply their efforts in
order to maintain the same response rate. Spam works. It is
not universally unwanted - which makes it tricky to outlaw. It
elicits between 0.1 and 1 percent in positive follow ups,
depending on the message. Many messages now include HTML,
JavaScript, and ActiveX coding and thus resemble viruses.
Jupiter Media Matrix predicted last year that the number of
spam messages annually received by a typical Internet user is
bound to double to 1400 and spending on legitimate e-mail
marketing will reach $9.4 billion by 2006 - compared to $1
billion in 2001. Forrester Research pegs the number at $4.8
billion next year.
More than 2.3 billion spam messages are sent daily. eMarketer
puts the figures a lot lower at 76 billion messages this year.
By 2006, daily spam output will soar to c. 15 billion
missives, says Radicati Group. Jupiter projects a more modest
268 billion annual messages by 2005. An average communication
costs the spammer 0.00032 cents.
PC World quotes the European Union as pegging the bandwidth
costs of spam worldwide at $8-10 billion annually. Other
damages include server crashes, time spent purging unwanted
messages, lower productivity, aggravation, and increased cost
of Internet access.
Inevitably, the spam industry gave rise to an anti-spam
industry. According to a Radicati Group report titled âAnti-virus, anti-spam, and content filtering market trends 2002-2006â, anti-spam revenues are projected to exceed $88 million
this year - and more than double by 2006. List blockers,
report and complaint generators, advocacy groups, registers of
known spammers, and spam filters all proliferate. The Wall
Street Journal reported in its June 25 issue about a
resurgence of anti-spam startups financed by eager venture
capital.
ISPâs are bent on preventing abuse - reported by victims - by
expunging the accounts of spammers. But the latter simply
switch ISPâs or sign on with free services like Hotmail and
Yahoo! Barriers to entry are getting lower by the day as the
costs of hardware, software, and communications plummet.
The use of e-mail and broadband connections by the general
population is spreading. Hundreds of thousands of
technologically-savvy operators have joined the market in the
last two years, as the dotcom bubble burst. Still, Steve
Linford of the UK-based Spamhaus.org insists that most spam
emanates from c. 80 large operators.
Now, according to Jupiter Media, ISPâs and portals are poised
to begin to charge advertisers in a tier-based system, replete
with premium services. Writing back in 1998, Bill Gates
described a solution also espoused by Esther Dyson, chair of
the Electronic Frontier Foundation:
âAs I first described in my book âThe Road Aheadâ in 1995, I
expect that eventually youâll be paid to read unsolicited email. Youâll tell your e-mail program to discard all
unsolicited messages that donât offer an amount of money that
youâll choose. If you open a paid message and discover itâs
from a long-lost friend or somebody else who has a legitimate
reason to contact you, youâll be able to cancel the payment.
Otherwise, youâll be paid for your time.â
Subscribers may not be appreciative of the joint ventures
between gatekeepers and inbox clutterers. Moreover, dominant
ISPâs, such as AT&T and PSINet have recurrently been accused
of knowingly collaborating with spammers. ISPâs rely on the
data traffic that spam generates for their revenues in an
ever-harsher business environment.
The Financial Times and others described how WorldCom refuses
to ban the sale of spamware over its network, claiming that it
does not regulate content. When âpinkâ (the color of canned
spam) contracts came to light, the implicated ISPâs blame the
whole affair on rogue employees.
PC World begs to differ:
âRonnie Scelson, a self-described spammer who signed such a
contract with PSInet, (says) that backbone providers are more
than happy to do business with bulk e-mailers. âIâve signed up
with the biggest 50 carriers two or three times,â says Scelson
⊠The Louisiana-based spammer claims to send 84 million
commercial e-mail messages a day over his three 45-megabit-per-second DS3 circuits. âIf you were getting $40,000 a month
for each circuit,â Scelson asks, âwould you want to shut me
down?â
The line between permission-based or âopt-inâ e-mail marketing
and spam is getting thinner by the day. Some list resellers
guarantee the consensual nature of their wares. According to
the Direct Marketing Associationâs guidelines, quoted by PC
World, not responding to an unsolicited e-mail amounts to
âopting-inâ - a marketing strategy known as âopting outâ. Most
experts, though,
Comments (0)