An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (ebook reader with highlighter txt) 📖
- Author: Adam Smith
- Performer: 0226763749
Book online «An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (ebook reader with highlighter txt) 📖». Author Adam Smith
interesting to the peace and welfare of civil society. They
gave birth, accordingly, to the two principal parties or sects
among the followers of the reformation, the Lutheran and
Calvinistic sects, the only sects among them, of which the
doctrine and discipline have ever yet been established by law in
any part of Europe.
The followers of Luther, together with what is called the church
of England, preserved more or less of the episcopal government,
established subordination among the clergy, gave the sovereign
the disposal of all the bishoprics, and other consistorial
benefices within his dominions, and thereby rendered him the real
head of the church; and without depriving the bishop of the right
of collating to the smaller benefices within his diocese, they,
even to those benefices, not only admitted, but favoured the
right of presentation, both in the sovereign and in all other lay
patrons. This system of church government was, from the
beginning, favourable to peace and good order, and to submission
to the civil sovereign. It has never, accordingly, been the
occasion of any tumult or civil commotion in any country in which
it has once been established. The church of England, in
particular, has always valued herself, with great reason, upon
the unexceptionable loyalty of her principles. Under such a
government, the clergy naturally endeavour to recommend
themselves to the sovereign, to the court, and to the nobility
and gentry of the country, by whose influence they chiefly expect
to obtain preferment. They pay court to those patrons, sometimes,
no doubt, by the vilest flattery and assentation ; but
fruquently, too, by cultivating all those arts which best
deserve, and which are therefore most likely to gain them, the
esteem of people of rank and fortune; by their knowledge in all
the different branches of useful and ornamental learning, by the
decent liberality of their manners, by the social good humour of
their conversation, and by their avowed contempt of those absurd
and hypocritical austerities which fanatics inculcate and pretend
to practise, in order to draw upon themselves the veneration, and
upon the greater part of men of rank and fortune, who avow that
they do not practise them, the abhorrence of the common people.
Such a clergy, however, while they pay their court in this manner
to the higher ranks of life, are very apt to neglect altogether
the means of maintaining their influence and authority with the
lower. They are listened to, esteemed, and respected by their
superiors; but before their inferiors they are frequently
incapable of defending, effectually, and to the conviction of
such hearers, their own sober and moderate doctrines, against the
most ignorant enthusiast who chooses to attack them.
The followers of Zuinglius, or more properly those of Calvin, on
the contrary, bestowed upon the people of each parish, whenever
the church became vacant, the right of electing their own pastor;
and established, at the same time, the most perfect equality
among the clergy. The former part of this institution, as long as
it remained in vigour, seems to have been productive of nothing
but disorder and confusion, and to have tended equally to corrupt
the morals both of the clergy and of the people. The latter part
seems never to have had any effects but what were perfectly
agreeable.
As long as the people of each parish preserved the right of
electing their own pastors, they acted almost always under the
influence of the clergy, and generally of the most factious and
fanatical of the order. The clergy, in order to preserve their
influence in those popular elections, became, or affected to
become, many of them, fanatics themselves, encouraged fanaticism
among the people, and gave the preference almost always to the
most fanatical candidate. So small a matter as the appointment of
a parish priest, occasioned almost always a violent contest, not
only in one parish, but in all the neighbouring parishes who
seldom failed to take part in the quarrel. When the parish
happened to be situated in a great city, it divided all the
inhabitants into two parties; and when that city happened, either
to constitute itself a little republic, or to be the head and
capital of a little republic, as in the case with many of the
considerable cities in Switzerland and Holland, every paltry
dispute of this kind, over and above exasperating the animosity
of all their other factions, threatened to leave behind it, both
a new schism in the church, and a new faction in the state.
In those small republics, therefore, the magistrate very soon
found it necessary, for the sake of preserving the public peace,
to assume to himself the right of presenting to all vacant
benefices. In Scotland, the most extensive country in which
this presbyterian form of church government has ever been
established, the rights of patronage were in effect abolished by
the act which established presbytery in the beginning of the
reign of William III. That act, at least, put in the power of
certain classes of people in each parish to purchase, for a very
small price, the right of electing their own pastor. The
constitution which this act established, was allowed to subsist
for about two-and-twenty years, but was abolished by the 10th of
queen Anne, ch.12, on account of the confusions and disorders
which this more popular mode of election had almost everywhere
occasioned. In so extensive a country as Scotland, however, a
tumult in a remote parish was not so likely to give disturbance
to government as in a smaller state. The 10th of queen Anne
restored the rights of patronage. But though, in Scotland, the
law gives the benefice, without any exception to the person
presented by the patron; yet the church requires sometimes (for
she has not in this respect been very uniform in her decisions) a
certain concurrence of the people, before she will confer upon
the presentee what is called the cure of souls, or the
ecclesiastical jurisdiction in the parish. She sometimes, at
least, from an affected concern for the peace of the parish,
delays the settlement till this concurrence can be procured. The
private tampering of some of the neighbouring clergy, sometimes
to procure, but more frequently to prevent this concurrence, and
the popular arts which they cultivate, in order to enable them
upon such occasions to tamper more effectually, are perhaps the
causes which principally keep up whatever remains of the old
fanatical spirit, either in the clergy or in the people of
Scotland.
The equality which the presbyterian form of church government
establishes among the clergy, consists, first, in the equality of
authority or ecclesiastical jurisdiction; and, secondly, in the
equality of benefice. In all presbyterian churches, the equality
of authority is perfect; that of benefice is not so. The
difference, however, between one benefice and another, is seldom
so considerable, as commonly to tempt the possessor even of the
small one to pay court to his patron, by the vile arts of
flattery and assentation, in order to get a better. In all the
presbyterian churches, where the rights of patronage are
thoroughly established, it is by nobler and better arts, that the
established clergy in general endeavour to gain the favour of
their superiors; by their learning, by the irreproachable
regularity of their life, and by the faithful and diligent
discharge of their duty. Their patrons even frequently complain
of the independency of their spirit, which they are apt to
construe into ingratitude for past favours, but which, at worse,
perhaps, is seldom anymore than that indifference which naturally
arises from the consciousness that no further favours of the kind
are ever to be expected. There is scarce, perhaps, to be
found anywhere in Europe, a more learned, decent, independent,
and respectable set of men, than the greater part of the
presbyterian clergy of Holland, Geneva, Switzerland, and
Scotland.
Where the church benefices are all nearly equal, none of them can
be very great; and this mediocrity of benefice, though it may be,
no doubt, carried too far, has, however, some very agreeable
effects. Nothing but exemplary morals can give dignity to a
man of small fortune. The vices of levity and vanity
necessarily render him ridiculous, and are, besides, almost as
ruinous to him as they are to the common people. In his own
conduct, therefore, he is obliged to follow that system of morals
which the common people respect the most. He gains their esteem
and affection, by that plan of life which his own interest and
situation would lead him to follow. The common people look upon
him with that kindness with which we naturally regard one who
approaches somewhat to our own condition, but who, we think,
ought to be in a higher. Their kindness naturally provokes
his kindness. He becomes careful to instruct them, and attentive
to assist and relieve them. He does not even despise the
prejudices of people who are disposed to be so favourable to him,
and never treats them with those contemptuous and arrogant airs,
which we so often meet with in the proud dignitaries of opulent
and well endowed churches. The presbyterian clergy, accordingly,
have more influence over the minds of the common people, than
perhaps the clergy of any other established church. It is,
accordingly, in presbyterian countries only, that we ever find
the common people converted, without persecution completely, and
almost to a man, to the established church.
In countries where church benefices are, the greater part of
them, very moderate, a chair in a university is generally a
better establishment than a church benefice. The
universities have, in this case, the picking and chusing of their
members from all the churchmen of the country, who, in every
country, constitute by far the most numerous class of men of
letters. Where church benefices, on the contrary, are many of
them very considerable, the church naturally draws from the
universities the greater part of their eminent men of letters;
who generally find some patron, who does himself honour by
procuring them church preferment. In the former situation, we
are likely to find the universities filled with the most eminent
men of letters that are to be found in the country. In the
latter, we are likely to find few eminent men among them, and
those few among the youngest members of the society, who are
likely, too, to be drained away from it, before they can have
acquired experience and knowledge enough to be of much use to it.
It is observed by Mr. de Voltaire, that father Por�e, a jesuit of
no great eminence in the republic of letters, was the only
professor they had ever had in France, whose works were worth the
reading. In a country which has produced so many eminent men of
letters, it must appear somewhat singular, that scarce one of
them should have been a professor in a university. The famous
Cassendi was, in the beginning of his life, a professor in the
university of Aix. Upon the first dawning of his genius, it was
represented to him, that by going into the church he could easily
find a much more quiet and comfortable subsistence, as well as a
better situation for pursuing his studies; and he immediately
followed the advice. The observation of Mr. de Voltaire may
be applied, I believe, not only to France, but to all other Roman
Catholic countries. We very rarely find in any of them an eminent
man of letters, who is a professor in a university, except,
perhaps, in the professions of law and physic; professions from
which the church is not so likely to draw them. After the church
of Rome, that of England is by far the richest and best endowed
church in Christendom. In England, accordingly, the church is
continually draining the universities of all their best and
ablest members; and an old college tutor who is known and
Comments (0)