An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (ebook reader with highlighter txt) 📖
- Author: Adam Smith
- Performer: 0226763749
Book online «An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (ebook reader with highlighter txt) 📖». Author Adam Smith
a sufficient indication of the ordinary state of debt and credit
between any two places, it would not from thence follow, that the
balance of trade was in favour of that place which had the
ordinary state of debt and credit in its favour. The ordinary
state of debt and credit between any two places is not always
entirely regulated by the ordinary course of their dealings with
one another, but is often influenced by that of the dealings of
either with many other places. If it is usual, for example, for
the merchants of England to pay for the goods which they buy of
Hamburg, Dantzic, Riga, etc. by bills upon Holland, the ordinary
state of debt and credit between England and Holland will not be
regulated entirely by the ordinary course of the dealings of
those two countries with one another, but will be influenced by
that of the dealings in England with those other places. England
may be obliged to send out every year money to Holland, though
its annual exports to that country may exceed very much the
annual value of its imports from thence, and though what is
called the balance of trade may be very much in favour of
England.
In the way, besides, in which the par of exchange has hitherto
been computed, the ordinary course of exchange can afford no
sufficient indication that the ordinary state of debt and credit
is in favour of that country which seems to have, or which is
supposed to have, the ordinary course of exchange in its favour ;
or, in other words, the real exchange may be, and in fact often
is, so very different from the computed one, that, from the
course of the latter, no certain conclusion can, upon many
occasions, be drawn concerning that of the former.
When for a sum or money paid in England, containing, according to
the standard of the English mint, a certain number of ounces of
pure silver, you receive a bill for a sum of money to be paid in
France, containing, according to the standard of the French mint,
an equal number of ounces of pure silver, exchange is said to be
at par between England and France. When you pay more, you are
supposed to give a premium, and exchange is said to be against
England, and in favour of France. When you pay less, you are
supposed to get a premium, and exchange is said to be against
France, and in favour of England.
But, first, We cannot always judge of the value of the current
money of different countries by the standard of their respective
mints. In some it is more, in others it is less worn, clipt, and
otherwise degenerated from that standard. But the value of the
current coin of every country, compared with that of any other
country, is in proportion, not to the quantity of pure silver
which it ought to contain, but to that which it actually does
contain. Before the reformation of the silver coin in King
William’s time, exchange between England and Holland, computed in
the usual manner, according to the standard of their respective
mints, was five-and twenty per cent. against England. But the
value of the current coin of England, as we learn from Mr
Lowndes, was at that time rather more than five-and-twenty per
cent. below its standard value. The real exchange, therefore, may
even at that time have been in favour of England, notwithstanding
the computed exchange was so much against it ; a smaller number
or ounces of pure silver, actually paid in England, may have
purchased a bill for a greater number of ounces of pure silver to
be paid in Holland, and the man who was supposed to give, may in
reality have got the premium. The French coin was, before the
late reformation of the English gold coin, much less wore than
the English, and was perhaps two or three per cent. nearer its
standard. If the computed exchange with France, therefore, was
not more than two or three per cent. against England, the real
exchange might have been in its favour. Since the reformation of
the gold coin, the exchange has been constantly in favour of
England, and against France.
Secondly, In some countries the expense of coinage is defrayed by
the government; in others, it is defrayed by the private people,
who carry their bullion to the mint, and the government even
derives some revenue from the coinage. In England it is defrayed
by the government; and if you carry a pound weight of standard
silver to the mint, you get back sixty-two shillings, containing
a pound weight of the like standard silver. In France a duty of
eight per cent. is deducted for the coinage, which not only
defrays the expense of it, but affords a small revenue to the
government. In England, as the coinage costs nothing, the current
coin can never be much more valuable than the quantity of bullion
which it actually contains. In France, the workmanship, as you
pay for it, adds to the value, in the same manner as to that of
wrought plate. A sum of French money, therefore, containing an
equal weight of pure silver, is more valuable than a sum of
English money containing an equal weight of pure silver, and must
require more bullion, or other commodities, to purchase it.
Though the current coin of the two countries, therefore, were
equally near the standards of their respective mints, a sum of
English money could not well purchase a sum of French money
containing an equal number of ounces of pure silver, nor,
consequently, a bill upon France for such a sum. If, for such a
bill, no more additional money was paid than what was sufficient
to compensate the expense of the French coinage, the real
exchange might be at par between the two countries; their debts
and credits might mutually compensate one another, while the
computed exchange was considerably in favour of France. If less
than this was paid, the real exchange might be in favour of
England, while the computed was in favour of France.
Thirdly, and lastly, In some places, as at Amsterdam, Hamburg,
Venice, etc. foreign bills of exchange are paid in what they call
bank money ; while in others, as at London, Lisbon, Antwerp,
Leghorn, etc. they are paid in the common currency of the
country. What is called bank money, is always of more value than
the same nominal sum of common currency. A thousand guilders in
the bank of Amsterdam, for example, are of more vallue than a
thousand guilders of Amsterdam currency. The difference between
them is called the agio of the bank, which at Amsterdam is
generally about five per cent. Supposing the current money of the
two countries equally near to the standard of their respective
mints, and that the one pays foreign bills in this common
currency, while the other pays them in bank money, it is evident
that the computed exchange may be in favour of that which pays in
bank money, though the real exchange should be in favour of that
which pays in current money; for the same reason that the
computed exchange may be in favour of that which pays in better
money, or in money nearer to its own standard, though the real
exchange should be in favour of that which pays in worse. The
computed exchange, before the late reformation of the gold coin,
was generally against London with Amsterdam, Hamburg, Venice,
and, I believe, with all other places which pay in what is called
bank money. It will by no means follow, however, that the real
exchange was against it. Since the reformation of the gold coin,
it has been in favour of London, even with those places. The
computed exchange has generally been in favour of London with
Lisbon, Antwerp, Leghorn, and, if you except France, I believe
with most other parts of Europe that pay in common currency ; and
it is not improbable that the real exchange was so too.
Digression concerning Banks of Deposit, particularly concerning
that of Amsterdam.
The currency of a great state, such as France or England,
generally consists almost entirely of its own coin. Should this
currency, therefore, be at any time worn, clipt, or otherwise
degraded below its standard value, the state, by a reformation of
its coin, can effectually re-establish its currency. But the
currency of a small state, such as Genoa or Hamburg, can seldom
consist altogether in its own coin, but must be made up, in a
great measure, of the coins of all the neighbouring states with
which its inhabitants have a continual intercourse. Such a state,
therefore, by reforming its coin, will not always be able to
reform its currency. If foreign bills of exchange are paid in
this currency, the uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its
own nature so uncertain, must render the exchange always very
much against such a state, its currency being in all foreign
states necessarily valued even below what it is worth.
In order to remedy the inconvenience to which this
disadvantageous exchange must have subjected their merchants,
such small states, when they began to attend to the interest of
trade, have frequently enacted that foreign bills of exchange of
a certain value should be paid, not in common currency, but by an
order upon, or by a transfer in the books of a certain bank,
established upon the credit, and under the protection of the
state, this bank being always obliged to pay, in good and true
money, exactly according to the standard of the state. The banks
of Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremberg, seem to have
been all originally established with this view, though some of
them may have afterwards been made subservient to other purposes.
The money of such banks, being better than the common currency of
the country, necessarily bore an agio, which was greater or
smaller, according as the currency was supposed to be more or
less degraded below the standard of the state. The agio of the
bank of Hamburg, for example, which is said to be commonly about
fourteen per cent. is the supposed difference between the good
standard money of the state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished
currency, poured into it from all the neighbouring states.
Before 1609, the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin
which the extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all parts of
Europe, reduced the value of its currency about nine per cent.
below that of good money fresh from the mint. Such money no
sooner appeared, than it was melted down or carried away, as it
always is in such circumstances. The merchants, with plenty of
currency, could not always find a sufficient quantity of good
money to pay their bills of exchange ; and the value of those
bills, in spite of several regulations which were made to prevent
it, became in a great measure uncertain.
In order to remedy these inconveniencies, a bank was established
in 1609, under the guarantee of the city. This bank received both
foreign coin, and the light and worn coin of the country, at its
real intrinsic value in the good standard money of the country,
deducting only so much as was neccssary for defraying the expense
of coinage and the other necessary expense of management. For the
value which remained after this small deduction was made, it gave
a credit in its books. This credit was called bank money, which,
as it represented money exactly according to the standard of the
mint, was always of the same real value, and intrinsically worth
more than current money. It was at the same time enacted, that
all bills drawn upon
Comments (0)